Desktop version

Home arrow Economics arrow Essentials of Macroeconomics

Growth Theories

The classical growth theory

The production function will not provide us with a theory or explanation of growth. It is only a convenient tool which helps us breaking down growth into its components. However, there are many growth theories that try to go a step further. The oldest of these theories is the so-called classical growth theory which is primarily associated with Thomas Robert Malthus.

The classical growth theory should not be confused with the classical model that we will look at in the next chapter. Also, the classical growth theory, which was developed in the late 1700s, has little or no relevance today. We present it so that you can better understand more modern growth theories.

In short, the classical growth theory may be described as follows:

1. Due to technological development, the amount of capital increases and the marginal product of labor rises.

2. GDP per capita rises. With higher living standards, the population will increase.

3. As population increases, the labor productivity will fall (more individuals but the same amount of capital).

4. GDP per capita will fall again. When GDP per capita has fallen to a level just high enough to keep the population from starving, the increase in population will cease.

Destruction of capital, for example, through a war, works in the opposite way. The marginal product of labor falls, GDP per capita falls and the population decreases. This will again lead to an increase in the marginal product of labor and GDP per capita return to the "survival rate".

The main point of the model is that population growth will always eliminate the positive effects of technological development and GDP per capita will always return to the survival level. This very "dismal" growth theory was prominent in the early 1800s, and economics to this day is sometimes called the "dismal science".

Today we know that the predictions of the model where incorrect. During the rest of the 1800s Europe experienced a growth in GDP per capita. Although the population growth was high, it was not nearly sufficient to eliminate the positive effects of technological development.

The neo-classical growth model

The main purpose of another important growth model, the neo-classical growth model, is to explain how it is possible to have a permanent growth in GDP per capita. The model was developed by Robert Solow in the 1960s and it is sometimes called the Solow growth model or the exogenous growth model.

The neo-classical growth model should not be confused with the neoclassical synthesis, which we will study in chapter 10. "Neo" means "new" - the neo-classical growth theory is a "new version" of the classical growth model.

The crucial difference between the classical and neo-classical growth model is that population is endogenous in the former and exogenous in the latter. In the classical model, population will increase or decrease depending on whether GDP per capita is higher than or lower than the survival level. In the neo-classical model population growth is not affected by GDP per capita (however, the population growth will affect the growth in GDP per capita).

In the neo-classical model, it is the technological progress only that affects the GDP per capita in the long run. We will have a permanent increase in GDP per capita when there is a technological development that increases productivity of labour. Permanent growth in GDP then requires continuous technological progress.

It is not possible for the government, except temporarily, to affect the growth rate in the neo-classical growth model. The government might be able to affect GDP per capita (and thus is the growth rate) but the growth rate always returns to the level determined by the technological progress. The same is true for savings. An increase in savings may have a temporary effect on GDP but it will have no effect in the long run.

Endogenous growth theory

Endogenous growth theory or new growth theory was developed in the 1980s by Paul Romer and others. In the neo-classical model, technological progress is an exogenous variable. The neo-classical growth model makes no attempt to explain how, when and why technological progress takes place.

The main objective of the endogenous growth theory is to make the technological progress an endogenous variable to be explained within the model, hence the name endogenous growth theory.

There are many different explanations for technological progress. Most of them, however, have a lot of common characteristics:

• They are based on constant return to scale for capital. Thus, MPK is not a decreasing function of K in these models.

• They consider technological development as a public good.

• They focus more on human capital.

• It is possible for the government to affect the growth rate. Higher savings also leads to higher growth, not just higher GDP per capita.

• They predict convergence of GDP per capita between countries in the long run. This is a consequence of the public good property of the technological developments.

Separation of growth and fluctuation

It is often useful to separate the evolution of a variable that grows over time into a trend and fluctuations around the trend. The graphs below show such a separation for real GDP.

Growth and the fluctuation around the trend.

Fig. 9.2: Growth and the fluctuation around the trend.

The left diagram shows a stylized graph of real GDP over time. It demonstrates the two important characteristics in real GDP. GDP fluctuates over time and GDP grows over time - at least over a longer period of time. The left graph is the sum of the middle graph and the right graph.

The middle graph shows the trend in GDP. The trend represents the second characteristic of GDP - the fact that GDP grows over time. The right graph shows the fluctuations around the trend (cycles) of GDP. These fluctuations around the trend represent the first property of GDP.

In macroeconomics it is common to study trends and cycles separately. The purpose of growth theory is to investigate the trend while most of macroeconomics apart from growth theory is about the cycles. The trend is about the very long run perspective of the economy while cycles are about the short and medium run. The rest of this is all about cycles and not at all about trends. Therefore, when you think of GDP in the remaining chapters, you should think of GDP as in the right-hand graph: GDP has cycles but no trend. Basically, we will study GDP where the trend has been removed.

 
Found a mistake? Please highlight the word and press Shift + Enter  
< Prev   CONTENTS   Next >

Related topics